New cryptocurrencies promise stability through ties to the dollar – but is it a myth?
The unpredictable nature of cryptocurrencies has prompted developers to turn to pegged alternatives. Unfortunately, the coins they tout are just as volatile
While the mania for cryptocurrencies may have peaked, new units continue to be announced, seemingly by the day. Prominent among the new arrivals are so-called ‘stablecoins’. Bearing names like Tether, Basis and Sagacoin, their value is rigidly tied to the dollar, the euro or a basket of national currencies.
It’s easy to see the appeal of these units: viable monies provide a reliable means of payment, unit of account and store of value. But conventional cryptocurrencies, such as bitcoin, trade at wildly fluctuating prices, which means that their purchasing power – their command over goods and services – is highly unstable. Hence, they are unattractive as units of account.
Face value
No grocer in their right mind would price the goods on their shelves in bitcoin. No worker would want a long-term employment contract that paid in a fixed number of those units. Furthermore, because their ability to command goods and services in the future similarly fluctuates wildly, cryptocurrencies like bitcoin are unattractive as a store of value. (Cryptocurrencies are also challenged as a means of payment, but leave that aside for the moment.)
Stablecoins purport to solve these problems. Because their value is stable in terms of dollars or their equivalent, they are attractive as units of account and stores of value. They are not mere vehicles for financial speculation.
But this doesn’t mean that they are viable. To understand why, it is useful to distinguish three types of stablecoin. The first type is fully collateralised: the operator holds reserves equalling or exceeding the value of the coins in circulation.
Tether, which is pegged one-to-one to the dollar, claims to hold dollar deposits equal to the value of its circulation. But the veracity of this claim has been disputed.
Conventional cryptocurrencies trade at wildly fluctuating prices, which means that their purchasing power is highly unstable
This points to yet another problem with this model: expense. To issue one dollar’s worth of Tether to you or me, the platform must attract one dollar of investment capital from you or me, and place it in a dollar bank account.
One of us will then have traded a perfectly liquid dollar, supported by the full faith and credit of the US Government, for a cryptocurrency with questionable backing that is awkward to use.
This exchange may be attractive to money launderers and tax evaders, but not to others. In other words, it is not obvious that the model will scale, or that governments will let it.
Closing the stable door
The second type of stablecoin is partly collateralised. In this case, the platform holds dollars equal to, say, 50 percent of the value of the coins in circulation. The problem with this variant will be familiar to any monetary policymaker whose central bank has sought to peg an exchange rate while holding reserves that are only a fraction of its liabilities.
If some coin owners harbour doubts about the durability of the peg, they will sell their holdings. The platform will have to purchase them using its dollar reserves to keep their price from falling.
But, because the stock of dollar reserves is limited, other investors will scramble to get out before the cupboard is bare. The result will be the equivalent of a bank run, leading to the collapse of the peg.
The third type of stablecoin, which is uncollateralised, has this problem in spades. Here, the platform issues not just crypto coins but also crypto bonds. If the price of the coins begins to fall, the platform buys them back in exchange for additional bonds.
The bonds are supposed to appeal to investors because they trade at a discount – so that, in principle, their price can rise – and because the issuer promises to pay interest to the bondholders in the form of additional coins. That interest is to be funded out of the income earned from future coin issuance.
Here, too, the flaw in the model will be obvious to even a novice central banker. The issuer’s ability to service the bonds depends on the growth of the platform, which is not guaranteed. If the outcome becomes less certain, the price of the bonds will fall.
More bonds will then have to be issued to prevent a given fall in the value of the coin, making it even harder to meet interest obligations. Under plausible circumstances, there may be no price, however low, that attracts willing buyers of additional bonds. Again, the result will be the collapse of the peg.
All of this will be familiar to anyone who has encountered even a single study of speculative attacks on pegged exchange rates, or to anyone who has had a coffee with an emerging-market central banker.
But this doesn’t mean that it is familiar to the wet-behind-the-ears software engineers touting stablecoins. And it doesn’t mean that the flaws in their currently fashionable schemes will be familiar to investors.
© Project Syndicate 2018